|
|
Line 553: |
Line 553: |
| | | | | |
| *[[NAE Case Study: Brazil, Luz para Todos (Light for All)|Brazil, Luz para Todos (Light for All)]] | | *[[NAE Case Study: Brazil, Luz para Todos (Light for All)|Brazil, Luz para Todos (Light for All)]] |
− | *[[NAE_Case_Study:_Peru,_Concession_Model_for_Standalone_Systems|Peru, Concession Model for Standalone Systems]]<br/> | + | *[[NAE Case Study: Peru, Concession Model for Standalone Systems|Peru, Concession Model for Standalone Systems]]<br/> |
| *[[NAE Case Study: Philippines, Islanded Distribution by Cooperatives|Philippines, Islanded Distribution by Cooperatives]]<br/> | | *[[NAE Case Study: Philippines, Islanded Distribution by Cooperatives|Philippines, Islanded Distribution by Cooperatives]]<br/> |
− | *[[NAE_Case_Study:_Tunisia,_Low_Cost_Distribution_Technology|Tunisia, Low Cost Distribution Technology]]<br/> | + | *[[NAE Case Study: Tunisia, Low Cost Distribution Technology|Tunisia, Low Cost Distribution Technology]]<br/> |
| *[[NAE Case Study: Vietnam, Rapid Grid Expansion|Vietnam, Rapid Grid Expansion]]<br/> | | *[[NAE Case Study: Vietnam, Rapid Grid Expansion|Vietnam, Rapid Grid Expansion]]<br/> |
| | | |
Line 574: |
Line 574: |
| <span>Any tax exemptions is effectively a grant or subsidy from government towards electricity provision, increasing affordability for users. It is particularly important to ensure that electricity is not disadvantages relative to other, less beneficial, forms of energy, such as kerosene by tax exemptions Three key forms of exemption are:</span><br/> | | <span>Any tax exemptions is effectively a grant or subsidy from government towards electricity provision, increasing affordability for users. It is particularly important to ensure that electricity is not disadvantages relative to other, less beneficial, forms of energy, such as kerosene by tax exemptions Three key forms of exemption are:</span><br/> |
| | | |
− | '''''<span></span>'''''<span style="font-size: 13.6px;">'''''Import tax''''' – import tax exemptions are used to incentivise renewable generation of electricity and deployment of off-grid systems for electrification in many countries (as seen in the </span>[[NAE_Case_Study:_Tunisia,_Low_Cost_Distribution_Technology|Tunisia]]<span style="font-size: 13.6px;">, </span>[[NAE_Case_Study:_Bangladesh,_IDCOL_Solar_Home_Systems|Bangladesh]]<span style="font-size: 13.6px;">, </span>[[NAE_Case_Study:_Ethiopia,_Solar_Market_Development|Ethiopia]]<span style="font-size: 13.6px;">, </span>[[NAE_Case_Study:_Mali,_Rural_Electrification_Programme|Mali]]<span style="font-size: 13.6px;"> </span><span style="font-size: 13.6px;">and </span>[[NAE_Case_Study:_Nepal,_Rural_Energy_Development_Programme|Nepal]]<span style="font-size: 13.6px;"> </span><span style="font-size: 13.6px;">NAE Case Studies).</span><br/> | + | '''''<span></span>'''''<span style="font-size: 13.6px;">'''''Import tax''''' – import tax exemptions are used to incentivise renewable generation of electricity and deployment of off-grid systems for electrification in many countries (as seen in the </span>[[NAE Case Study: Tunisia, Low Cost Distribution Technology|Tunisia]]<span style="font-size: 13.6px;">, </span>[[NAE Case Study: Bangladesh, IDCOL Solar Home Systems|Bangladesh]]<span style="font-size: 13.6px;">, </span>[[NAE Case Study: Ethiopia, Solar Market Development|Ethiopia]]<span style="font-size: 13.6px;">, </span>[[NAE Case Study: Mali, Rural Electrification Programme|Mali]]<span style="font-size: 13.6px;"> </span><span style="font-size: 13.6px;">and </span>[[NAE Case Study: Nepal, Rural Energy Development Programme|Nepal]]<span style="font-size: 13.6px;"> </span><span style="font-size: 13.6px;">NAE Case Studies).</span><br/> |
| | | |
− | '''''<span style="font-size: 13.6px;"></span>'''''<span style="font-size: 13.6px;">'''''Value Added Tax'''''– electricity itself is often VAT exempt, but electricity costs may still be impacted significantly by VAT charged on equipment and services used in electricity provision. This negative impact of VAT has been recognised and addressed in several countries. The NAE Case studies from </span>[[NAE_Case_Study:_Kenya,_Off-Grid_for_Vision_2030|Kenya]]<span style="font-size: 13.6px;"> </span><span style="font-size: 13.6px;">and </span>[[NAE_Case_Study:_Tanzania,_Mini-Grids_Regulatory_Framework|Tanzania]]<span style="font-size: 13.6px;"> </span><span style="font-size: 13.6px;">for example show that in these countries VAT has been removed on solar products, while in Senegal and the Seychelles there is tax exemption for any renewable energy equipment.</span> | + | '''''<span style="font-size: 13.6px;"></span>'''''<span style="font-size: 13.6px;">'''''Value Added Tax'''''– electricity itself is often VAT exempt, but electricity costs may still be impacted significantly by VAT charged on equipment and services used in electricity provision. This negative impact of VAT has been recognised and addressed in several countries. The NAE Case studies from </span>[[NAE Case Study: Kenya, Off-Grid for Vision 2030|Kenya]]<span style="font-size: 13.6px;"> </span><span style="font-size: 13.6px;">and </span>[[NAE Case Study: Tanzania, Mini-Grids Regulatory Framework|Tanzania]]<span style="font-size: 13.6px;"> </span><span style="font-size: 13.6px;">for example show that in these countries VAT has been removed on solar products, while in Senegal and the Seychelles there is tax exemption for any renewable energy equipment.</span> |
| | | |
| <span>'''''Corporate taxes''''' – taxes charged on electricity businesses and their operations reduce returns available to investors. By reducing these taxes, governments can enable businesses to charge lower prices while maintaining acceptable levels of returns, and to extend electricity provision into areas where it might otherwise not be economically sustainable. This approach has been demonstrated in Zambia for example.</span><br/> | | <span>'''''Corporate taxes''''' – taxes charged on electricity businesses and their operations reduce returns available to investors. By reducing these taxes, governments can enable businesses to charge lower prices while maintaining acceptable levels of returns, and to extend electricity provision into areas where it might otherwise not be economically sustainable. This approach has been demonstrated in Zambia for example.</span><br/> |
Line 657: |
Line 657: |
| | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(49, 49, 152);" | <br/> | | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(49, 49, 152);" | <br/> |
| | | | | |
− | If private finance is attracted, it can support rapid electrification at a large scale, and can free up public funding to be used for other things. If market conditions are such as to attract purely private finance, this indicates that the electrification process will be self-sustaining without dependence upon external grants or subsidies from the government or donor organisations. Where customers are able to pay for electricity at a level that allows the supply to be maintained under market conditions, there is no concern over the withdrawal of public funding that may then prevent continued access to electricity. Experience also indicates that involvement of private finance can drive innovation and efficiencies in electrification as in other sectors.
| + | There are advantages to project developers, investors, local communities and to Government from the provision of tax exemptions for activities related to electrification. For developers and their financiers, the reduced cost of system components and related materials means that projects can be more cost effective, with upfront costs reduced to provide lower investment risk – this can be the difference between the developer achieving access to finance and not. For local communities, electricity can be offered at a lower price since the costs have been reduced. And for Government, the reduced income from tax payments is may be balanced by the reduced need for Government expenditure to provide a basic service for remote households; the project developers can now meet this demand, which otherwise would have required the allocation of public services budget from the Government. |
| | | |
− | Private finance, however, requires clear evidence that revenues will provide returns on investment, and this may be an insurmountable barrier, particularly for forms of electrification such as grid and mini-grid systems which have high upfront capital costs that will be recovered over long periods (perhaps 20 years). Even where macro-economic conditions are stable, regulatory frameworks and prices/tariffs transparent, and users able to afford electricity, financiers may be reluctant to provide support in the absence of established companies with a track record of performance. Much time and effort may be expended in the attempt to attract sufficient private finance without the required results. Furthermore, private finance is usually more expensive than general government borrowing and this will particularly be the case for programmes that are seen by the financiers as carrying significant levels of risk.
| + | Tax exemptions may seem less painful than explicit grants and subsidies, since they do not require any payment from government, but they nevertheless represent a reduction in government revenues. This may also carry the downside of lack of transparency. Moreover tax exemptions represent a relatively blunt instrument and care must be taken to ensure that it is those who would not otherwise be able to afford electricity, and not the relatively affluent, who benefit. Most problems related to tax exemptions, however, arise from their implementation. Establishing clear criteria for their application can be difficult and lack of clarity (to the officials involved as well as to the potential recipients) can lead to inconsistency, delays, costs and frustrations that undermine the positive intentions. Implementation also requires awareness, cooperation and understanding of electrical technology and standards from officials such a customs officers who would not normally have much involvement or interest in the electricity sector. |
| | | |
| |} | | |} |
Line 671: |
Line 671: |
| | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(49, 49, 152);" | <br/> | | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(49, 49, 152);" | <br/> |
| | | | | |
− | *De Montfort University (2013), Financing Energy Access and Off-grid Electrification: A Review of Status, Options and Challenges [https://www.dmu.ac.uk/documents/technology-documents/research-faculties/oasys/project-outputs/peer-reviewed-journal-articles/pj7--financing-energy-access--rser-paper.pdf https://www.dmu.ac.uk/documents/technology-documents/research-faculties/oasys/project-outputs/peer-reviewed-journal-articles/pj7--financing-energy-access--rser-paper.pdf] | + | *IRENA (2016), Policies and Regulations for Private Sector Renewable Energy Mini-Grids <u>[http://www.irena.org/DocumentDownloads/Publications/IRENA_Policies_Regulations_minigrids_2016.pdf http://]</u><u>[http://www.irena.org/DocumentDownloads/Publications/IRENA_Policies_Regulations_minigrids_2016.pdf www.irena.org/DocumentDownloads/Publications/IRENA_Policies_Regulations_mini-grids_2016.pdf]</u> |
− | *UNEP-FI (2012), Financing renewable energy in developing countries [http://www.unepfi.org/fileadmin/documents/Financing_Renewable_Energy_in_subSaharan_Africa.pdf http://www.unepfi.org/fileadmin/documents/Financing_Renewable_Energy_in_subSaharan_Africa.pdf]
| + | |
| | | |
| |} | | |} |
|
Technology
|
Most national grid systems are constructed using public funds, though private finance can be introduced through privatisation of existing assets, inviting private generators to feed into the national grid, or establishment of distribution/grid-connected mini-grid concessions. For instance, the introduction of feed-in tariffs (e.g. in Tanzania) has provided the basis for private investment in generation. Mini-grids are more frequently, though by no means always, financed by the private sector since the smaller investment and shorter payback period can reduce the risks and provides a more manageable business opportunity. Stand-alone systems offer even greater opportunities for market-based finance since the relatively short period between purchase and sale to the user means that that only business establishment and a small amount of equipment capital investment is at risk.
|
|
Delivery Models
|
Application of market-based finance, by definition, requires private sector ownership or a public-private partnership (PPP). PPPs are often an effective way to attract private finance since the public-sector element can offer funding and offset the risk associated with financing of electrification. Any private or PPP financing will require a business model with clear investment requirements and projections of income that provide expected return on investment over an acceptable timeframe, and with acceptable levels of risk and uncertainty.
|
|
Legual Basis
|
Any private finance provider will consider the legal basis of electrification in terms of the risk profile it presents to them. The lower the risk and the greater certainty, the more likelihood that private finance will be available and at a lower cost. The most fundamental requirement for any private investment in fixed assets is clarity around the legality of operating and selling electricity. This may be provided explicitly through a concession or license, or through a general exclusion of certain types of electricity provision (e.g. mini-grids below a certain size) from the need to be licensed. Without this basic regulatory clarity, and so with the risk that future introduction of regulation may undermine their business and restrict their levels of income, it will be extremely difficult to attract private finance for electrification.
|
|
Price/Tariff Regulation
|
Is a critical factor for private investment in electrification, with inadequate or inappropriate price/tariff regulation often cited as the key barrier to such finance. Whatever form of price/tariff regulation is used the critical requirement is that it is clear and transparent, as without this, private financiers will see a significant risk of political pressure reducing prices or tariffs to the point below which they fail to cover investment costs.
|
|
Other Forms of Finance
|
In many cases some other form(s) of public finance such as grants, subsidies, concessionary loans, tax exemptions or guarantees (to reduce investment risks) will be needed alongside private finance to overcome the lack of user spending power and the high costs of early market development.
User Finance – Charges paid by users provide the means to repay electricity providers’ loans and equity investments and pay interest and return on capital. Where upfront charges are imposed on users, they may in turn seek to borrow to cover these charges and then repay the loan over time. Alternatively the electricity provider may seek additional finance in order to reduce up-front charges and so minimize barriers to users accessing their services.
|
|
Non-Financial Interventions
|
Most support activities to assist national electrification will reduce the perceived financial risk and so help to attract private sector investment and sustainable market development. Providing policies and targets, standards and technical assistance for new electrification initiatives will all increase the private financier’s certainty regarding the likely outcomes and so reduce the risk of investment. Market information, capacity building and customer engagement through promotional activity will all have a similar positive effect.
|
|
Technology
|
Grid system construction and extension is highly capital intensive and almost all national grids (including those in developed countries) are constructed using public funding from government, sometimes supplemented by concessionary loans and grants from international agencies. The bulk of ongoing grid funding generally comes from users charges, but the grid is often seen as a national asset and electricity from it as a public good supporting national economic development, and governments may therefore choose to provide continuing subsidies either on a general basis, to incentivize extension to new users, or fund provision to specific groups of users (eg through lifeline tariffs). The primary financing for mini-grids will generally align with the delivery model, with publically-owned mini-grids using public finance and privately owned mini-grids drawing on private finance. However, where incomes are lower or system costs higher, grants and /or subsidies are likely to be needed to make electricity from mini-grids affordable to users and the mini-grid businesses economically sustainable. Standalone systems are most frequently provided commercially and purchased directly by users. Grants may be used, as seen in the NAE Case Study of the IDCOL programme in Bangladesh, to make systems more affordable to users, to enable providers to establish their businesses and to fund support activities. Where standalone system providers are moving towards pay-as-you-go arrangements their need for capital will increase and it may be more appropriate to channel grants and subsidies to them, allowing them to reduce monthly charges and charges to users for electricity used. Standalone systems may also, as can be seein in the NAE Case Study South Africa, be provided through a public delivery model and subsidized through that model.
|
|
Delivery Models
|
By definition, any public delivery model will use public finance - effectively government (and international ) grants and subsidies – combined with finance from users, while a purely private delivery model must be purely privately financed (since inclusion of any grants or subsidies finance would cause the delivery model to be categorized as a public-private partnership). All public-private partnership models will involve a combination of private and public finance, frequently through explicit grants and subsidies (or tax exemptions or guarantees) or through partial public ownership acting as a form of grant /subsidy.
|
|
Legual Basis
|
A concession may be used as a means of channelling grants or subsidies into electricity provision through the terms of the concession agreement. A license would not generally be linked directly to a grant or subsidy, but may be one of the qualifying requirements for accessing them. Grants and subsidies will most often be linked to some form of regulation to ensure proper use of funds.
|
|
Price/Tariff Regulation
|
Any price/tariff regulation must factor in grants or subsidies received by the electricity business, so that their effect is to reduce prices or tariffs and make electricity more affordable to users. This also serves to ensure proper use of public funding and so where grants and subsidies are made available, prices or tariffs are more likely to be regulated. Where combined with a uniform price/tariff arrangement, grants and subsidies may make electricity access more affordable, but if they, too, are set on a uniform basis, while they may extend the group of users to whom electricity can be economically provided, they are also likely to create additional excess profits for those elements of electricity provision which could have been delivered economically at a lower subsidy level. This implies that where uniform prices or tariffs are used, grants or subsidies should be structured to reflect costs of provision. Where prices or tariffs are set on an individual basis, the prices/tariffs themselves can be made cost-reflective. Where prices/tariffs are unregulated, it is left to market competition to ensure that grants and subsidies are passed to the users rather than unnecessarily retained by the business to boost profits to excessive levels.
|
|
Other Forms of Finance
|
Private Finance – private finance will depend upon the investor’s (or lender’s) assessment of the financial return and the level of risk involved. Grants and subsidies can directly increase probable return and reduce risk by off-setting costs and increasing demand by making electricity affordable for more users. Indirectly grant-funded technical assistance, local capacity-building, awareness-raising, and promotion of uses of electricity by potential customers can also make investment in electricity access more attractive to private financiers.
User finance – grants or subsidies paid to users provide one source of user finance, allowing users to off-set up-front and/or ongoing charges. Grants and subsidies paid to electricity businesses have the same effect indirectly. Because grants and subsidies do not require repayment they provide an absolute reduction in users’ need to secure other forms of finance, not just a timing shift.
Cross-subsidies – sit alongside grants and subsidies as finance which is not derived from commercial investment in the specific electricity provider or payments from the users being supplied. They may therefore be seen as an alternative to grants and subsidies, but it must be recalled that they are taken from other businesses and users and so, unlike grants and subsidies simply redistribute the costs of electricity rather than reducing them
Tax exemptions and Guarantees – Act as indirect forms of grant or subsidy by reducing costs and risks
|
|
Non-Financial Interventions
|
Direct provision of electricity can act as a vehicle for grants and subsidies if it is undertaken at below cost, or if it uses funding (eg from the public purse) which is not required to be repaid. Grants may be used to fund other non-financial interventions, such as technical assistance and awareness raising. (Non-financial interventions undertaken at no cost to the electricity provider could also be regarded as grants or subsidies, but are not treated as such in categorizing NEA).
|
The Review was prepared by Mary Willcox and Dean Cooper of Practical Action Consulting working with Hadley Taylor, Silvia Cabriolu-Poddu and Christina Stuart of the EU Energy Initiative Partnership Dialogue Facility (EUEIPDF) and Michael Koeberlein and Caspar Priesemann of the Energising Development Programme (EnDev). It is based on a literature review, stakeholder consultations. The categorization framework in the review tool is based on the EUEI/PDF / Practical Action publication "Building Energy Access Markets - A Value Chain Analysis of Key Energy Market Systems".
A wider range of stakeholders were consulted during its preparation and we would particularly like to thank the following for their valuable contributions and insights:
- Jeff Felten, AfDB - Marcus Wiemann and other members, ARE - Guilherme Collares Pereira, EdP - David Otieno Ochieng, EUEI-PDF - Silvia Luisa Escudero Santos Ascarza, EUEI-PDF - Nico Peterschmidt, Inensus - John Tkacik, REEEP - Khorommbi Bongwe, South Africa: Department of Energy - Rashid Ali Abdallah, African Union Commission - Nicola Bugatti, ECREEE - Getahun Moges Kifle, Ethiopian Energy Authority - Mario Merchan Andres, EUEI-PDF - Tatjana Walter-Breidenstein, EUEI-PDF - Rebecca Symington, Mlinda Foundation - Marcel Raats, RVO.NL - Nico Tyabji, Sunfunder -