|
|
Line 9: |
Line 9: |
| <p style="text-align: center;"><span style="color:#316798ff;">'''Delivery Model: The (market) chain of organisations through which electricity is delivered to users'''</span></p> | | <p style="text-align: center;"><span style="color:#316798ff;">'''Delivery Model: The (market) chain of organisations through which electricity is delivered to users'''</span></p> |
| ---- | | ---- |
− |
| |
− | <br/>
| |
| | | |
| <br/> | | <br/> |
Line 24: |
Line 22: |
| '''<span></span><span>Delivery of electricity access by an entity or entities all of which are publically owned and managed, using purely public finance.</span><span></span>''' | | '''<span></span><span>Delivery of electricity access by an entity or entities all of which are publically owned and managed, using purely public finance.</span><span></span>''' |
| | | |
− | <span>In this delivery model all of the organisations engaged in provision of electricity access (whether through supply of electricity itself or provision of electricity systems), as part of the National Electrification Approach being considered, are state-owned. This implies that all the actors along the market chain1 (Project Development, Manufacture/Generation, Distribution and Retail) are publically owned. These may include electricity utilities, publically-owned generation, transmission and distribution companies, municipalities, or rural energy agencies. </span><span></span><br/> | + | <span>In this [[Delivery_Models_for_Decentralised_Rural_Electrification|delivery model]] all of the organisations engaged in provision of electricity access (whether through supply of electricity itself or provision of electricity systems), as part of the National Electrification Approach being considered, are state-owned. This implies that all the actors along the market chain (Project Development, Manufacture/Generation, Distribution and Retail) are publically owned. These may include electricity utilities, publically-owned generation, transmission and distribution companies, municipalities, or rural energy agencies. </span><span></span><br/> |
| | | |
| |} | | |} |
Line 41: |
Line 39: |
| | | |
| | style="width: 616px;" | | | | style="width: 616px;" | |
− | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span>National grid systems have most often been established under a public delivery model either through a single public electricity company owning and managing the entire system or through separate public generation, transmission and distribution companies. Grid-connected mini-grids and distribution systems may also be publically owned, for instance by a local municipality. Where isolated mini-grids or standalone systems are delivered through a public model this is generally by an electricity utility or distribution company which has adopted an integrated approach with electricity being provided using a combination of grid, mini-grid and standalone systems.<br/> | + | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span>[[Portal:Grid|National grid]] systems have most often been established under a public delivery model either through a single public electricity company owning and managing the entire system or through separate public generation, transmission and distribution companies. Grid-connected [[Portal:Mini-grid|mini-grids]] and distribution systems may also be publically owned, for instance by a local municipality. Where isolated mini-grids or standalone systems are delivered through a public model this is generally by an electricity utility or distribution company which has adopted an integrated approach with electricity being provided using a combination of grid, mini-grid and standalone systems.<br/> |
| | | |
| |- | | |- |
Line 71: |
Line 69: |
| | | |
| | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> | | | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> |
− | <span>By definition, a public delivery model will use public finance – by publically-owned utility companies or national or local government, potentially supported by loans and grants from international agencies - (since any private finance would cause the delivery model to be categorized as a public-private partnership). In addition public delivery models will draw on finance from users, through standalone system purchases, connection charges and ongoing charges, and for multi-user systems (grids and mini-grids) there is likely to be some element of cross-subsidy between users.</span><span></span> | + | <span>By definition, a public delivery model will use public finance – by publically-owned utility companies or national or local government, potentially supported by loans and grants from international agencies - (since any private finance would cause the delivery model to be categorized as a public-private partnership). In addition public delivery models will draw on finance from users, through standalone system purchases, connection charges and ongoing charges, and for multi-user systems ([[Portal:Grid|grids]] and [[Portal:Mini-grid|mini-grids]]) there is likely to be some element of cross-subsidy between users.</span><span></span> |
| | | |
| |- | | |- |
Line 93: |
Line 91: |
| | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 152, 203);" | <br/> | | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 152, 203);" | <br/> |
| | | | | |
− | A public delivery model has the advantage of making use of existing institutions. Where these organisations have strong capabilities and are efficient, a public delivery model may allow strongly focussed and effective delivery of electrification and good coordination of grid, mini-grid and stand-alone solutions. However public organisations are often monolithic and slow moving. They may be more focussed on managing existing assets than serving new consumers, particularly in remote rural areas, and they may lack the capabilities needed to deliver new forms of electricity access. They are also vulnerable to political pressure and interference, which can hamper electrification efforts and result in poor allocation of resources. Following a private sector or private-public partnership model can allow private sector finance and skills to be brought to bear and may achieve greater flexibility, speed and efficiency. | + | A public delivery model has the advantage of making use of existing institutions. Where these organisations have strong capabilities and are efficient, a public delivery model may allow strongly focussed and effective delivery of electrification and good coordination of [[Portal:Grid|grid]], [[Portal:Mini-grid|mini-grid]] and stand-alone solutions. However public organisations are often monolithic and slow moving. They may be more focussed on managing existing assets than serving new consumers, particularly in remote rural areas, and they may lack the capabilities needed to deliver new forms of electricity access. They are also vulnerable to political pressure and interference, which can hamper electrification efforts and result in poor allocation of resources. Following a private sector or private-public partnership model can allow private sector finance and skills to be brought to bear and may achieve greater flexibility, speed and efficiency. |
| | | |
| |} | | |} |
Line 159: |
Line 157: |
| | | |
| | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> | | | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> |
− | Few, if any, national grid systems have been established through a private delivery model (though in many countries privatisation has been used to transfer them into private ownership and bring in private investment). Grid-connected mini-grids and distribution systems have frequently been developed by private (non-state-owned) organisations. Where the grid system is also privately-owned, this constitutes a private model. (However, if the grid system is publically owned, and the mini-grid or distribution system uses electricity from the grid system, or the development draws on public grants, subsidies, loans, tax exemptions or guarantees, it constitutes a public-private partnership). The most frequently used models for delivery of standalone systems are private, though involvement of state-organisations along the market chain, or use of funding from grants or subsidies provided by the state, donors or international agencies, may result in private-public partnerships. | + | Few, if any, national [[Portal:Grid|grid]] systems have been established through a private delivery model (though in many countries privatisation has been used to transfer them into private ownership and bring in private investment). Grid-connected [[Portal:Mini-grid|mini-grids]] and distribution systems have frequently been developed by private (non-state-owned) organisations. Where the grid system is also privately-owned, this constitutes a private model. (However, if the grid system is publically owned, and the mini-grid or distribution system uses electricity from the grid system, or the development draws on public grants, subsidies, loans, tax exemptions or guarantees, it constitutes a public-private partnership). The most frequently used models for delivery of standalone systems are private, though involvement of state-organisations along the market chain, or use of funding from grants or subsidies provided by the state, donors or international agencies, may result in private-public partnerships. |
| | | |
| |- | | |- |
Line 169: |
Line 167: |
| | | |
| | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> | | | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> |
− | A private delivery model calls for an explicit legal framework for any form of electrification which involves significant long-term capital investment (grid, mini-grids and potentially standalone systems which are charged for on a pay-as-you-go basis) in order to attract private finance and allow for price regulation to protect users. A concession, which offers protection from competition, will provide the greatest attraction for private financiers. Where no long-term capital investment is involved, as with standalone systems sold directly to users, it’s generally considered that no legal control (beyond that for any business) is necessary. <br/> | + | A private delivery model calls for an explicit legal framework for any form of electrification which involves significant long-term capital investment ([[Portal:Grid|grid]], [[Portal:Mini-grid|mini-grids]] and potentially standalone systems which are charged for on a pay-as-you-go basis) in order to attract private finance and allow for price regulation to protect users. A concession, which offers protection from competition, will provide the greatest attraction for private financiers. Where no long-term capital investment is involved, as with standalone systems sold directly to users, it’s generally considered that no legal control (beyond that for any business) is necessary. <br/> |
| | | |
| |- | | |- |
Line 179: |
Line 177: |
| | | |
| | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> | | | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> |
− | Where electricity is delivered by the private sector, using purely private finance, in a competitive market with no legal or effective monopoly (eg where several solar lanterns providers are operating) price regulation may be regarded as unnecessary. However, where any form of concession has been granted (or exists in practice), price regulation would be expected to protect users. On the other side, where significant capital investment is involved private financiers are likely to require a transparent framework for price/tariff regulation, to reduce the risk of price controls being introduced in the future at below cost-recovery levels and preventing full recovery of and return on investment. | + | Where electricity is delivered by the private sector, using purely private finance, in a competitive market with no legal or effective monopoly (eg where several [[Basic_Energy_Services_-_Solar_PV_(SHS,_Solar_Lanterns)|solar lanterns]] providers are operating) price regulation may be regarded as unnecessary. However, where any form of concession has been granted (or exists in practice), price regulation would be expected to protect users. On the other side, where significant capital investment is involved private financiers are likely to require a transparent framework for price/tariff regulation, to reduce the risk of price controls being introduced in the future at below cost-recovery levels and preventing full recovery of and return on investment. |
| | | |
| |- | | |- |
Line 189: |
Line 187: |
| | | |
| | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> | | | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> |
− | As discussed above a private delivery model must be purely privately financed (since inclusion of any public finance would cause the delivery model to be categorized as a public-private partnership). Ultimately private delivery models will rely on connection and ongoing charges, and standalone system purchases from users. For multi-user systems (grids and mini-grids) there is also likely to be some element of cross-subsidy between users.<span style="font-size: 13.6px;"> </span> | + | As discussed above a private delivery model must be purely privately financed (since inclusion of any public finance would cause the delivery model to be categorized as a public-private partnership). Ultimately private delivery models will rely on connection and ongoing charges, and standalone system purchases from users. For multi-user systems ([[Portal:Grid|grids]] and [[Portal:Mini-grid|mini-grids]]) there is also likely to be some element of cross-subsidy between users.<span style="font-size: 13.6px;"> </span> |
| | | |
| |- | | |- |
Line 211: |
Line 209: |
| | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 204, 248);" | <br/> | | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 204, 248);" | <br/> |
| | | | | |
− | The private sector is widely seen as being more efficient, innovative flexible and nimble that the public sector and it is these virtues that it brings to energy access provision. Use of a private delivery model can be a way of bringing private sector skills and finance (both national and international), and the benefits of competition into the energy sector. Where public institutions are weak and ineffective, private delivery models may seem attractive, but it must be recognised that successful private delivery relies (particularly for grids and mini-grids) on effective public management including strong regulatory frameworks and this calls for capabilities within public institutions which they may lack. There are also elements needed for the private sector to deliver, such as workforce skills and user awareness, which individual businesses may be reluctant to provide, because of the costs involved and because in a competitive market <span style="font-size: 13.6px;">they will be unsure that they (rather than competitors) will capture the benefits and secure a return on their investment. </span><span style="font-size: 13.6px;">In addition, where modern energy access is not affordable on a purely private financed basis or public financial input is </span><span style="font-size: 13.6px;">needed to support the costs of early market development, a public-private partnership delivery model will be needed. </span><span style="font-size: 13.6px;">Grid-connected mini-grids can, in theory, provide any level of electricity supply, but in most cases if the investment is made for grid connection and associated standards are met, they provide a grid-equivalent service, meeting all household, commercial, industrial and community requirements (Tier 5). (If the grid system itself is over-stretched with inadequate generation; or insufficiently robust or poorly maintained transmission and distribution systems reliability and quality of supply may deteriorate so that while users have a physical connection, they may not in fact have reliable access to electricity (bringing the supply Tier 3 or lower). To the extent that a grid-connected mini-grid draws on electricity from the grid its construction should be coupled with development of additional centralized generation capacity to support the resulting additional demand.</span> | + | The private sector is widely seen as being more efficient, innovative flexible and nimble that the public sector and it is these virtues that it brings to energy access provision. Use of a private delivery model can be a way of bringing private sector skills and finance (both national and international), and the benefits of competition into the energy sector. Where public institutions are weak and ineffective, private delivery models may seem attractive, but it must be recognised that successful private delivery relies (particularly for [[Portal:Grid|grids]] and [[Portal:Mini-grid|mini-grids]]) on effective public management including strong regulatory frameworks and this calls for capabilities within public institutions which they may lack. There are also elements needed for the private sector to deliver, such as workforce skills and user awareness, which individual businesses may be reluctant to provide, because of the costs involved and because in a competitive market <span style="font-size: 13.6px;">they will be unsure that they (rather than competitors) will capture the benefits and secure a return on their investment. </span><span style="font-size: 13.6px;">In addition, where modern energy access is not affordable on a purely private financed basis or public financial input is </span><span style="font-size: 13.6px;">needed to support the costs of early market development, a public-private partnership delivery model will be needed. </span><span style="font-size: 13.6px;">Grid-connected mini-grids can, in theory, provide any level of electricity supply, but in most cases if the investment is made for grid connection and associated standards are met, they provide a grid-equivalent service, meeting all household, commercial, industrial and community requirements (Tier 5). (If the grid system itself is over-stretched with inadequate generation; or insufficiently robust or poorly maintained transmission and distribution systems reliability and quality of supply may deteriorate so that while users have a physical connection, they may not in fact have reliable access to electricity (bringing the supply Tier 3 or lower). To the extent that a grid-connected mini-grid draws on electricity from the grid its construction should be coupled with development of additional centralized generation capacity to support the resulting additional demand.</span> |
| | | |
| |} | | |} |
Line 280: |
Line 278: |
| | | |
| | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> | | | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> |
− | Public-private models for grid systems might include: | + | Public-private models for [[Portal:Grid|grid]] systems might include: |
| | | |
| *Publically owned generation and transmission combined with privately owned distribution;<br/> | | *Publically owned generation and transmission combined with privately owned distribution;<br/> |
Line 286: |
Line 284: |
| *<span style="font-size: 13.6px;">A privately owned grid system using grants from public sources to connect new users.</span> | | *<span style="font-size: 13.6px;">A privately owned grid system using grants from public sources to connect new users.</span> |
| | | |
− | <span style="font-size: 13.6px;">For grid connected mini-grids and distribution systems:</span><br/> | + | <span style="font-size: 13.6px;">For grid connected [[Portal:Mini-grid|mini-grids]] and distribution systems:</span><br/> |
| | | |
| *Mini-grids owned by a private developer connected to the (publically-owned) main grid, and thereby drawing on publically owned generation to meet demand;<br/> | | *Mini-grids owned by a private developer connected to the (publically-owned) main grid, and thereby drawing on publically owned generation to meet demand;<br/> |
Line 328: |
Line 326: |
| | | |
| | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> | | | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> |
− | All public-private partnerships will involve a combination of private and public finance. Private finance will come through ownership and investment in, and loans to electricity providers. Public finance may come through these routes, but may also be through various forms of grant, subsidy, tax exemption or guarantee. Ultimately public-private models, like other forms of electricity provision, will rely on connection and ongoing charges, and standalone system purchases from users. For multi-user systems (grids and mini-grids) there is also likely to be some element of cross-subsidy between users. | + | All public-private partnerships will involve a combination of private and public finance. Private finance will come through ownership and investment in, and loans to electricity providers. Public finance may come through these routes, but may also be through various forms of grant, subsidy, tax exemption or guarantee. Ultimately public-private models, like other forms of electricity provision, will rely on connection and ongoing charges, and standalone system purchases from users. For multi-user systems ([[Portal:Grid|grids]] and [[Portal:Mini-grid|mini-grids]]) there is also likely to be some element of cross-subsidy between users. |
| | | |
| |- | | |- |
Line 402: |
Line 400: |
| | | |
| [[Category:NAE]] | | [[Category:NAE]] |
| + | [[Category:Energy_Access]] |
| + | [[Category:Grid]] |
| + | [[Category:Mini-grid]] |
The Review was prepared by Mary Willcox and Dean Cooper of Practical Action Consulting working with Hadley Taylor, Silvia Cabriolu-Poddu and Christina Stuart of the EU Energy Initiative Partnership Dialogue Facility (EUEIPDF) and Michael Koeberlein and Caspar Priesemann of the Energising Development Programme (EnDev). It is based on a literature review, stakeholder consultations. The categorization framework in the review tool is based on the EUEI/PDF / Practical Action publication "Building Energy Access Markets - A Value Chain Analysis of Key Energy Market Systems".
A wider range of stakeholders were consulted during its preparation and we would particularly like to thank the following for their valuable contributions and insights:
- Jeff Felten, AfDB - Marcus Wiemann and other members, ARE - Guilherme Collares Pereira, EdP - David Otieno Ochieng, EUEI-PDF - Silvia Luisa Escudero Santos Ascarza, EUEI-PDF - Nico Peterschmidt, Inensus - John Tkacik, REEEP - Khorommbi Bongwe, South Africa: Department of Energy - Rashid Ali Abdallah, African Union Commission - Nicola Bugatti, ECREEE - Getahun Moges Kifle, Ethiopian Energy Authority - Mario Merchan Andres, EUEI-PDF - Tatjana Walter-Breidenstein, EUEI-PDF - Rebecca Symington, Mlinda Foundation - Marcel Raats, RVO.NL - Nico Tyabji, Sunfunder -