|
|
Line 215: |
Line 215: |
| *UNEP & GOGLA, (2015), Developing Effective Off-Grid Lighting Policy <u>[https://www.gogla.org/sites/www.gogla.org/files/recource_docs/developing-effective-off-grid-lighting-policy.pdf https://www.gogla.org/sites/www.gogla.org/files/recource_docs/developing-effective-off-grid-lighting-policy.pdf]</u><br/> | | *UNEP & GOGLA, (2015), Developing Effective Off-Grid Lighting Policy <u>[https://www.gogla.org/sites/www.gogla.org/files/recource_docs/developing-effective-off-grid-lighting-policy.pdf https://www.gogla.org/sites/www.gogla.org/files/recource_docs/developing-effective-off-grid-lighting-policy.pdf]</u><br/> |
| *WBCSD, Business Case for Low-Carbon Microgrids (2016) <u>[http://www.ifc.org/wps/wcm/connect/topics_ext_content/ifc_external_corporate_site/ifc+sustainability/learning+and+adapting/knowledge+products/publications/publications_report_gap-opportunity http://www.ifc.org/wps/wcm/connect/topics_ext_content/ifc_external_corporate_site/ifc+sustainability/learning+ and+adapting/knowledge+products/publications/publications_report_gap-opportunity]</u><br/> | | *WBCSD, Business Case for Low-Carbon Microgrids (2016) <u>[http://www.ifc.org/wps/wcm/connect/topics_ext_content/ifc_external_corporate_site/ifc+sustainability/learning+and+adapting/knowledge+products/publications/publications_report_gap-opportunity http://www.ifc.org/wps/wcm/connect/topics_ext_content/ifc_external_corporate_site/ifc+sustainability/learning+ and+adapting/knowledge+products/publications/publications_report_gap-opportunity]</u><br/> |
− | *World Resources Institute (2015),Clean Energy Access in Developing Countries: Perspectives on Policy and Regulation, Issue Brief 2 <u>[https://www.irena.org/DocumentDownloads/Publications/Evaluating_policies_in_support_of_the_deployment_of_renewable_power.pdf https://www.irena.org/DocumentDownloads/Publications/Evaluating_policies_in_support_of_the_ deployment_of_renewable_power.pdf]</u><br/> | + | *World Resources Institute (2015),Clean Energy Access in Developing Countries: Perspectives on Policy and Regulation, Issue Brief 2<u>[https://www.irena.org/DocumentDownloads/Publications/Evaluating_policies_in_support_of_the_deployment_of_renewable_power.pdf https://www.irena.org/DocumentDownloads/Publications/Evaluating_policies_in_support_of_the_ deployment_of_renewable_power.pdf]</u> |
| | | |
| |} | | |} |
Line 223: |
Line 223: |
| == Relevante Case Studies: == | | == Relevante Case Studies: == |
| | | |
− | *[[NAE Case Study: Brazil, Luz para Todos (Light for All)|Brazil, Luz para Todos (Light for All)]]<br/>
| + | None of the examples examined have had a purely private sector delivery models (ie no public involvement in either ownership or funding). |
− | *[[NAE Case Study: Cambodia “Light Touch” Regulation|Cambodia “Light Touch” Regulation]]<br/>
| + | |
− | *[[NAE Case Study: Costa Rica, Distribution Cooperatives|Costa Rica, Distribution Cooperatives]]<br/>
| + | |
− | *[[NAE Case Study: Rwanda, Sector-Wide Approach to Planning|Rwanda, Sector-Wide Approach to Planning]]<br/>
| + | |
− | *[[NAE Case Study: Tanzania, Mini-Grids Regulatory Framework|Tanzania, Mini-Grids Regulatory Framework]]<br/>
| + | |
− | *[[NAE Case Study: Vietnam, Rapid Grid Expansion|Vietnam, Rapid Grid Expansion]]<br/>
| + | |
| | | |
| <br/> | | <br/> |
| | | |
− | = Isolated Mini-Grids = | + | = Public-Private Partnership Delivery Model = |
| | | |
| {| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;" | | {| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;" |
| |- | | |- |
− | | style="width: 130px; background-color: rgb(103, 153, 0);" | | + | | style="width: 130px; background-color: rgb(100, 203, 248);" | |
| '''<span style="color:#FFFFFF;"><span style="font-size: 13.6px;">Definition:</span></span>'''<br/> | | '''<span style="color:#FFFFFF;"><span style="font-size: 13.6px;">Definition:</span></span>'''<br/> |
| | | |
| | style="width: 618px;" | | | | style="width: 618px;" | |
− | '''<span><span>A system for generation and distribution of electricity to multiple users which is not connected to the main grid system.</span></span>''' | + | '''Delivery of electricity access by an entity which is part publically and part privately owned or by a mix of publically and privately owned entities or using a combination of public and private finance'''<br/> |
| | | |
− | Mini-grids exist at a wide range of scales, from those supplying a few households to systems covering several communities. Isolated mini-grids rely on one or more local, usually small-scale (diesel, bioenergy, biomass, hydro, solar, wind or hybrid), generating plants and must balance demand and generation at all times. While these include fossil-fuel based generation, technology advances combined with environmental concerns mean that policy-makers are increasingly focussing on encouraging Renewable Energy based generation. Being separated from the grid system, isolated mini-grids can used lower voltages and lower-cost technologies than the main grid, and may be designed to provide anything from lighting alone (a “skinny grid”) to a full grid-equivalent electricity service. <br/>
| + | This includes cases where: |
| + | |
| + | *a joint venture has been created between a state-owned organisation and a private company to provide electricity<br/> |
| + | *one or more state-owned organisation fill some of the functions along the market chain1, while others are filled by private businesses<br/> |
| + | *electricity provision is undertaken by private businesses with public financial support (subsidies, grants, loans etc) |
| | | |
| |} | | |} |
Line 252: |
Line 251: |
| {| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;" | | {| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;" |
| |- | | |- |
− | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(103, 153, 0);" | <br/> | + | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(100, 203, 248);" | <br/> |
− | | style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(51, 103, 152);" | | + | | style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(0, 101, 0);" | |
− | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Delivery Model</span><br/> | + | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Technologies</span><br/> |
| | | |
| <br/> | | <br/> |
| | | |
| | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> | | | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> |
− | Isolated mini-grids are often privately owned, but may be publically owned or combine both in a public-private partnership. Common models include:
| + | Public-private models for grid systems might include: |
| + | |
| + | *Publically owned generation and transmission combined with privately owned distribution;<br/> |
| + | *Independent Power Producers (IPPs) connected to a publically owned transmission/distribution system;<br/> |
| + | *<span style="font-size: 13.6px;">A privately owned grid system using grants from public sources to connect new users.</span> |
| + | |
| + | <span style="font-size: 13.6px;">For grid connected mini-grids and distribution systems:</span><br/> |
| | | |
− | *An isolated mini-grid owned by a private developer, a user-cooperative or community organisation;<br/> | + | *Mini-grids owned by a private developer connected to the (publically-owned) main grid, and thereby drawing on publically owned generation to meet demand;<br/> |
− | *Mini-grids owned and operated by the national grid company in off-grid areas;<br/> | + | *A private company, or public-private joint venture, taking on operation of a section of the publically-owned grid distribution system;<br/> |
− | *A mini-grid operated by a municipality or other local public entity to supply an off-grid community;<br/> | + | *Public grants or subsidies supporting development of a privately-owned mini-grid or distribution system.<br/> |
− | *Isolated mini-grids developed under a Public-Private Partnership, for instance on a Build-Own-Operate-Transfer basis. | + | |
| + | For isolated mini-grids: |
| + | |
| + | *Mini-grids developed on a Build-Own-Operate-Transfer basis (initially owned and operated by a private developer, but transferred to public ownership at the end of a concession period);<br/> |
| + | *Mini-grids built and operated by a public-private joint venture;<br/> |
| + | *Public grants or subsidies supporting development of a privately-owned mini-grid. |
| + | |
| + | Use of public finance (grants, subsidies and loans) to enhance affordability and support market growth often results in a public-private model for standalone systems, even when there is a purely private-sector chain of manufacturers, importers, distributors and retailers. There could also be benefits in some circumstances from government energy agencies becoming directly involved in the standalone system market, by forming a joint entity to supply systems or by taking on one of the roles along the value chain (eg providing a distribution service for all system providers), as a means of supporting market development. |
| | | |
| |- | | |- |
Line 274: |
Line 286: |
| | | |
| | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> | | | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> |
− | Mini-grids require substantial, long-term, capital investment and hence a regulatory framework which will give developers, and particularly private financiers, confidence that there will be a market for electricity from the mini-grid for a long enough period to repay and provide an adequate return on their investment. Larger systems may require concessions (which protect against competition over a designated area and time period) to give investors the confidence in revenue forecasts to commit the long-term capital investment needed. For smaller mini-grids, with lower and shorter-term capital investment, a licensing regime (which grants a non-exclusive right to sell electricity) may be more appropriate, with greater flexibility and a generally less demanding process balancing lack of protection from competition for the investor, while still providing the means to protect users through price/tariff regulation and setting technical and safety standards. Mini-grids below a certain size (eg <100kW in the [[NAE Case Study: Tanzania, Mini-Grids Regulatory Framework|Tanzania NAE Case Study]]), are often unregulated, as the administrative burden (and costs) of regulation are seen as disproportionate to the protection it would provide to investors and users, and the right to operate instead being granted through a general derogation from regulation.
| + | Because a public-private model involves private ownership and investment, an explicit legal framework will be required for any form of electrification which involves significant long-term capital investment in order to attract private finance and allow for price regulation to protect users. A concession, which offers protection from competition, will provide the greatest attraction for private financiers. Where no long-term capital investment is involved, as with standalone systems sold directly to users, no legal control (beyond that for any business) may be necessary – however if there is partial public sector ownership, a transparent legal framework <span style="font-size: 13.6px;">may be required to convince private market participants that they are not facing unfair competition, and also to ensure that </span><span style="font-size: 13.6px;">any public finance is not being misused. </span> |
− | | + | |
− | Under any regulatory regime a key question for private mini-grid investors will be what happens when the main grid arrives? Grid extension into a mini-grid concession area within the concession period may be prohibited by the terms of the concession, or there may be explicit provision for compensation and transfer of assets to grid ownership. mini-grid licensees have less protection from grid extension than concessionaires, but even where there is no formal concession it is often beneficial to establish a compensation regime in the event of grid extension, to encourage private mini-grid investment in the interim.
| + | |
− | | + | |
− | Where mini-grids are delivered through a public model with purely public finance, the legal basis will generally be less critical as public financiers are less likely to be concerned about recovery of and return on investment through future revenues.
| + | |
| | | |
| |- | | |- |
Line 288: |
Line 296: |
| | | |
| | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> | | | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> |
− | Isolated mini-grids rely on revenues from the sale of electricity to users to cover ongoing operating, maintenance and administrative costs and repayment and return on investment. Regulation of tariff levels is therefore a critical factor for private investors in mini-grids, with inadequate or inappropriate tariff regulation often cited as the key barrier to mini-grid investment.<br/>
| + | Where significant capital investment is involved, a transparent framework for price/tariff regulation is likely to be required to attract the private element into any public-private partnership. Tariff regulation will also protect users and provide a means of ensuring that public finance is not being misused or exploited by the private sector. It may also demonstrate to private market participants that they are not facing unfair competition from partially publically-owned market participants. |
− | | + | |
− | A uniform-tariff regime, where all mini-grid operators must charge the same tariffs, has the attraction of apparent equity, but will generally encourage investment only in those areas where electricity can be supplied at a lower cost allowing the investor to retain a margin and discourage investment in harder to supply areas (unless public funding/subsidy, or cross-subsidies, are made available to overcome higher costs). Individually set tariffs, based on costs specific to individual mini-grid contexts, are more likely to encourage investments in more remote areas.
| + | |
− | | + | |
− | Whatever form of tariff regulation is used the critical requirement is that it is clear and transparent, to reduce project development costs and give private financiers confidence that revenues from mini-grids are not vulnerable to arbitrary regulatory decisions and political pressure.
| + | |
| | | |
| |- | | |- |
Line 302: |
Line 306: |
| | | |
| | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> | | | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> |
− | Financing for isolated mini-grids will generally align with the delivery model, with publically-owned mini-grids using public finance and privately owned mini-grids drawing on private finance. However, where incomes are lower or system costs higher, some form of public-private partnership is likely to be needed with public funding (eg through grants and subsidies) making electricity from mini-grids affordable to users and the mini-grid systems economically sustainable.
| + | All public-private partnerships will involve a combination of private and public finance. Private finance will come through ownership and investment in, and loans to electricity providers. Public finance may come through these routes, but may also be through various forms of grant, subsidy, tax exemption or guarantee. Ultimately public-private models, like other forms of electricity provision, will rely on connection and ongoing charges, and standalone system purchases from users. For multi-user systems (grids and mini-grids) there is also likely to be some element of cross-subsidy between users. |
− | | + | |
− | User charges are the other main source of funding with connection charges and ongoing tariffs are used to contribute to investment, cover ongoing operating costs and support repayment and return on investment. As with any system supplying multiple users, there is likely to be some element of cross-subsidy between users connected to any individual mini-grid system. Cross-subsidy between isolated mini-grids or between the main grid and mini-grid systems may be appropriate, particularly if a uniform tariff is applied.
| + | |
| | | |
| |- | | |- |
Line 314: |
Line 316: |
| | | |
| | style="width: 616px;" | | | | style="width: 616px;" | |
− | National energy planning and sharing of market information are key to establishing the planned<br/>extent and timescales for grid extension and hence the scope for isolated mini-grids. Regulatory reform and policy and target-setting are likely to be required to create the framework for isolated mini-grids to be developed. Capacity building or technical assistance may be beneficial where potential developers lack necessary skills and capabilities. User awareness raising and demand promotion are often essential to increase revenues and make mini-grids economically sustainable.<br/> | + | National energy planning is key to establishing the optimum mix of technologies to meet electrification needs across the country, regardless of the delivery model employed. Institutional restructuring may be needed to establish public-private partnerships and capacity building or technical assistance may be required if the key actors lack the capacity to undertake regulatory reform or design arrangements for public financial support. Awareness raising amongst users and other potential market actors and service providers, as well as training (capacity building) to develop the skilled workforce needed by new energy access businesses can be beneficial alongside financial forms of public support. Public-private partnership may also provide the means to bring in new technology, with the private sector providing the technology know-how while the public sector bears the risk inherent in new technology which private investors may be reluctant to take on. <br/> |
| | | |
| |} | | |} |
− |
| |
− | <br/>
| |
| | | |
| <br/> | | <br/> |
Line 328: |
Line 328: |
| | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(103, 153, 0);" | <br/> | | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(103, 153, 0);" | <br/> |
| | | | | |
− | Mini-grids are most appropriate for relatively densely populated areas with higher demand levels which are distant from the grid system, particularly where there is a good local source of energy for electricity generation. Because mini-grids rely on local, small-scale, generation, and their demand profiles often have pronounced peaks (because their users want electricity at the same times of day), their generating costs are usually higher than costs of electricity from larger power plants connected to the main grid, so in areas closer to the grid, where the cost of connecting to the grid is relatively low, grid extension will usually be more economic. In sparsely populated low-demand areas, standalone systems, despite their higher generating costs, may be more economic because they avoid the cost of a distribution system. mini-grids may also, even in areas for which grid extension would be more economic in the longer term, provide a means for achieving energy access more quickly.
| + | Public-Private partnerships offer the potential to combine the benefits of both models, with public security being combined with private efficiency, innovation and flexibility. Bringing in private finance can extend the capacity for electricity provision beyond that which the public sector alone can offer, while public financial support can be used to attract private finance and make electricity affordable for users. Combining public and private inputs is not, however, simple. Significant expertise is required to ensure that private investment is attracted while making optimum use of public resources. Moreover the appropriate form of public-private partnership will change as markets develop and levels of electricity access increase – and this must be recognised while at the same time creating regimes which can give the private sector the confidence in the future they require to invest. |
− | | + | |
− | Mini-grids may be designed to provide any level of electricity access, from “skinny-grid”, which just support lighting and, perhaps phone-charging (Tier 1) to a grid-equivalent service, meeting all household, commercial, industrial and community requirements (Tier 5). In many more remote communities where isolated mini-grids are the most appropriate solution, it is a Tier 2-3 level (to support medium power appliances such as fans, refrigerators, small water pumps and hand tools). In theory, the grid system which is able to call on multiple sources of generation should be more reliable than an isolated mini-grid, but in practice if the grid system itself is over-stretched with inadequate generation; or insufficiently robust or poorly maintained transmission and distribution systems, reliability and quality of supply may deteriorate so that while users have a physical connection they may not in fact have reliable access to electricity. Poor grid reliability is one of the reasons many users turn to mini-grids and standalone systems even in areas where grid connection is available.
| + | |
| | | |
| |} | | |} |
Line 342: |
Line 340: |
| | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(103, 153, 0);" | <br/> | | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(103, 153, 0);" | <br/> |
| | | | | |
− | *ARE. 2014. Hybrid Mini-Grids for Rural Electrification - Lessons Learned [https://ruralelec.org/sites/default/files/hybrid_mini-grids_for_rural_electrification_2014.pdf https://][https://ruralelec.org/sites/default/files/hybrid_mini-grids_for_rural_electrification_2014.pdf ruralelec.org/sites/default/files/hybrid_mini-grids_for_rural_electrification_2014.pdf] | + | *<span style="font-size: 16pt; font-family: "Calibri Light";">Clean </span><span style="font-size: 16pt; font-family: "Calibri Light";">Energy Solutions Centre & </span><span style="font-size: 16pt; font-family: "Calibri Light";">iied</span><span style="font-size: 16pt; font-family: "Calibri Light";">. (2015). Policies to Spur Energy </span><span style="font-size: 16pt; font-family: "Calibri Light";">Access<u><span style="font-size: 16pt; font-family: "Calibri Light";">[https://cleanenergysolutions.org/resources/policies-spur-energy-access https]</span></u><u><span style="font-size: 16pt; font-family: "Calibri Light";">[https://cleanenergysolutions.org/resources/policies-spur-energy-access ://]</span></u><u><span style="font-size: 16pt; font-family: "Calibri Light";">[https://cleanenergysolutions.org/resources/policies-spur-energy-access cleanenergysolutions.org/resources/policies-spur-energy-access]</span></u></span> |
− | *<div>ESMAP (2005), Meeting the Challenge of Rural Electrification in Developing Nations: The Experience of Successful Programs [https://static.globalinnovationexchange.org/s3fs-public/asset/document/Meeting0the0Ch10Discussion0Version0.pdf?q3Tol9Bdn4yH4J43t3P9t3hq5lh6ZipT https://][https://static.globalinnovationexchange.org/s3fs-public/asset/document/Meeting0the0Ch10Discussion0Version0.pdf?q3Tol9Bdn4yH4J43t3P9t3hq5lh6ZipT static.globalinnovationexchange.org/s3fs-public/asset/document/Meeting0the0Ch10Discussion0Version0.pdf?q3Tol9Bdn4yH4J43t3P9t3hq5lh6ZipT]</div>
| + | |
− | *<div><span>EUEI </span><span>PDF (2014), Mini-grid Policy Toolkit: Policy and Business Frameworks for Successful Mini-grid Roll-outs [http://www.euei-pdf.org/sites/default/files/field_publication_file/RECP_MiniGrid_Policy_Toolkit_1pageview_(pdf,_17.6MB,_EN_0.pdf http://www.euei-pdf.org/sites/default/files/field_publication_file/RECP_MiniGrid_Policy_Toolkit_1pageview_(pdf,_17.6MB,_EN_0.pdf] </span><br/></div>
| + | |
− | *<div><span></span>IRENA (2016), Innovation Outlook: Renewable Mini-grids, International Renewable Energy Agency, Abu Dhabi [http://www.irena.org/DocumentDownloads/Publications/IRENA_Innovation_Outlook_Minigrids_2016.pdf http://][http://www.irena.org/DocumentDownloads/Publications/IRENA_Innovation_Outlook_Minigrids_2016.pdf www.irena.org/DocumentDownloads/Publications/IRENA_Innovation_Outlook_Minigrids_2016.pdf]</div>
| + | |
− | *IRENA (2016), Policies and regulations to support renewable energy mini-grid [http://www.irena.org/DocumentDownloads/Publications/IRENA_Policies_Regulations_minigrids_2016.pdf http://][http://www.irena.org/DocumentDownloads/Publications/IRENA_Policies_Regulations_minigrids_2016.pdf www.irena.org/DocumentDownloads/Publications/IRENA_Policies_Regulations_minigrids_2016.pdf]<br/>
| + | |
− | *World Bank. 2014. From the Bottom Up. How Small Power Producers and Mini-Grids Can Deliver Electrification and Renewable Energy in Africa. [https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/16571 https://][https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/16571 openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/16571]
| + | |
| | | |
| |} | | |} |
None of the examples examined have had a purely private sector delivery models (ie no public involvement in either ownership or funding).
The Review was prepared by Mary Willcox and Dean Cooper of Practical Action Consulting working with Hadley Taylor, Silvia Cabriolu-Poddu and Christina Stuart of the EU Energy Initiative Partnership Dialogue Facility (EUEIPDF) and Michael Koeberlein and Caspar Priesemann of the Energising Development Programme (EnDev). It is based on a literature review, stakeholder consultations. The categorization framework in the review tool is based on the EUEI/PDF / Practical Action publication "Building Energy Access Markets - A Value Chain Analysis of Key Energy Market Systems".
A wider range of stakeholders were consulted during its preparation and we would particularly like to thank the following for their valuable contributions and insights:
- Jeff Felten, AfDB - Marcus Wiemann and other members, ARE - Guilherme Collares Pereira, EdP - David Otieno Ochieng, EUEI-PDF - Silvia Luisa Escudero Santos Ascarza, EUEI-PDF - Nico Peterschmidt, Inensus - John Tkacik, REEEP - Khorommbi Bongwe, South Africa: Department of Energy - Rashid Ali Abdallah, African Union Commission - Nicola Bugatti, ECREEE - Getahun Moges Kifle, Ethiopian Energy Authority - Mario Merchan Andres, EUEI-PDF - Tatjana Walter-Breidenstein, EUEI-PDF - Rebecca Symington, Mlinda Foundation - Marcel Raats, RVO.NL - Nico Tyabji, Sunfunder -